Snow melts in the rain. The river is high, and after a period of freeze, it rushes again with a new kind of excitement. The blue heron reveals its image, first near the bridge in Island Park, then under the mulberry tree, and then on the diverted water at Argo Dam (I haven't seen him since summer), while nuthatches move about swiftly and cheerfully as usual calling my attention from treetops. But today my mind is with some great minds in economics.

From Ibn Khaldoun to Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Joseph Schumpeter, John Maynard Keynes, Sir Arthur Lewis, Kenneth Arrow, Robert Solow, Robert Lucas Jr. and Yifu Lin, each pondered on the concept of economic growth, each sought to understand what drive economic growth, and each significantly advanced our understandings about economic growth (from capital accumulation, labor and consumption to trade, institutions and technology). Nonetheless, today as a few western nations enjoy the fruits of economic development (which slows down now, by the way), the majority of developing countries are not successful so far in making the transition to the developed world. While social scientists and activists are fighting slums in India, Indonesia, Africa and Latin America, the anxiety of fearing for a potential economic crisis has never gone away in China despite its fast continuous economic growth in the past two decades. And we are facing more and more severe environmental problems across the globe and increasing inequality in wealth among human populations.

I agree with Dale Jorgenson that Solow might have been wrong in estimating how much economic growth was attributed to technology advances, but I do not necessarily agree with Dale Jorgenson's estimates either. It's simple: economic growth is an outcome of the interplay between many factors and forces (dependent on the development history as well), and I am not positive that we can single out the effects of one from others quantitatively despite our technical advancements in statistics (econometrics). It may not be necessary or important to do so.

Each place/country has its unique characteristics in natural and human resources, accumulated wealth, technology level, political system, history and culture while imbedded in a global network. This is the picture we should keep in mind when we set out to search a development strategy for sustained economic growth. And this analysis of economic growth is the foundation for the larger sustainability science, in which we look at human well-being (beyond GDP) and treat the environment as an endogenous entity instead of externality (especially we need to investigate its long-term feedbacks to human well-being). Human-environment systems should be the basic units of analysis in sustainability science then. A human-environment system can be a local place, a region or a nation, and each is a node in an interconnected network with horizontal and vertical links to others. The whole globe is a human-environment system by itself, the largest in scale, and the most complex of all complex systems. I am convinced that sustainability is all about how large a scope and how far ahead we see - focusing on short-term local interests will get us nowhere near but only further away from sustainability.

An important goal of sustainability science is, then, to understand how social-economic-political-environmental factors and forces interact with one another to shape human well-being over time in human-environment systems at both local and global scales. The sustainability science is therefore a synthesis of many sciences: economics, political science, sociology, cognitive science, environmental science...

(i)       What kinds of human societies could grow given the natural resource endowment and the current population, technology level and wealth?

(ii)     What policies could induce the emergence of better societies (that is, in which sustained equitable economic growth increases overall human well-being)?

(iii)   And equally (if not more) important, how to avoid disastrous future outcomes?

Today, on my walk, it appears ever clearer that seeking for theoretical and empirical understandings to these questions is worth a life time.

 

P.S. At the entrance to Bird Hills from Kuebler Langford Park (where golden leaves weave a beautiful carpet on an ascending slope every autumn), the sun came out, and the sky threw open its magnificent mantle in an exuberant blue. If I could, I would set the cello right then right there on those ascending stairs to play Bach's suite No.6.

 

(As the last piece of a series written for solo cello by Bach, No.6 conveys such a sense of unlimited possibilities and extraordinary freedom to explore even under the shadow of death.)

 

 

Previous

Next